Since 2007, the importance of foreign financing of Poland’s external debt has systematically increased. Between 2007 and 2014, the nominal value of Polish public debt (calculated as per the place of debt issuance) more than doubled: from PLN 124 billion to PLN 292 billion, while the share of foreign debt in total sovereign debt rose from 24% to 35%. The involvement of foreign investors in Polish sovereign debt is also on the rise – they are more and more eager to buy not just the public debt issued abroad, but also Poland’s domestically issued debt. At the end of 2014, more than half of Poland’s debt was held by foreign investors (PLN 472 billion, i.e. 57% of government debt). Back in 2008, their share was a mere 34%. A particularly rapid growth of Polish debt in foreign hands was noted in 2009–11. At the end of 2008, its value totalled at PLN 201 billion, at the end of 2011 – already at PLN 401 billion. The increase in the foreign share in Poland’s sovereign debt was also influenced by the 2014 redemption of bonds held by open pension funds (OFE), which resulted in lowering the assets of the domestic non-bank sector.
Polish sovereign debt in 2007–14: breakdown by place of issuance (in PLN billion)
Breakdown | 2007 | 2008 | 2009 | 2010 | 2011 | 2012 | 2013 | 2014 |
foreign | 124 | 154 | 176 | 205 | 258 | 264 | 268 | 292 |
domestic | 403 | 443 | 494 | 543 | 557 | 576 | 614 | 535 |
share of foreign debt in sovereign debt | 24% | 26% | 26% | 27% | 32% | 31% | 30% | 35% |
Source: own analysis based on the data of the Ministry of Finance.
Polish sovereign debt in 2007–14: breakdown by sector of debt holder (in PLN billion)
Breakdown | 2007 | 2008 | 2009 | 2010 | 2011 | 2012 | 2013 | 2014 |
foreign investors | 192 | 201 | 250 | 323 | 401 | 446 | 449 | 472 |
domestic non-bank sector | 219 | 227 | 229 | 245 | 243 | 243 | 255 | 135 |
domestic bank sector | 116 | 170 | 191 | 180 | 172 | 152 | 178 | 220 |
share of foreign investors in sovereign debt | 36% | 34% | 37% | 43% | 49% | 53% | 51% | 57% |
Source: own analysis based on the data of the Ministry of Finance.
The growing role of non-residents in financing Polish sovereign debt has its source in the relatively low domestic savings, which – given the state’s ever greater borrowing needs resulting from chronically unbalanced public finances – limits domestic demand for treasury securities. Foreign financing does not engender the crowding out effect, which consists in limiting domestic investment as a result of the available (already moderate) funds being absorbed by the public sector. At the same time, quantitative easing programmes implemented in other countries, which stimulate demand for emerging market bonds (and Poland is still classified as one), have been conducive to the inflow of foreign capital. In view of the high foreign demand and increased scope of issue of Polish bonds on foreign markets (characterised by low interest rates), interest on Poland’s debt is gradually becoming lower. The average interest rate of 10-year bonds dropped from 6.1% in 2008 to 3.5% in 2014. Foreign debt is also characterised by longer maturities than domestic debt: in 2014, the average maturity of foreign debt amounted to 7.1 years, and domestic debt – to 4.2 years.
Nevertheless, the growing importance of foreign financing of Poland’s external debt should be viewed with a dose of scepticism. Economic literature indicates that the public authorities’ growing reliance on foreign markets in terms of debt issuance, driven mostly by lower financing costs, may be extremely dangerous. Foreign debt exposure has been the fundamental cause of several debt crises, e.g. those affecting Mexico and Argentina in the 1990s.
The process of increasing the share of foreign sources of financing Poland’s debt has led, among others, to a significant increase in the share of foreign currency in State Treasury debt: from 24% in 2007 to 35% in 2014 (parallel to the share of foreign debt). This, in turn, entails exposing public finances to exchange rate risk. We are dealing here with the same mechanism that affected Polish households which have taken out mortgages denominated in Swiss franc – on the one hand, the debt is equipped with a lower interest rate than domestic debt, on the other, if the zloty weakens against the currency in which the debt is denominated, the value of such debt and its servicing costs increase. At the end of 2014, 25% of the State Treasury’s debt was denominated in euro, 7% in US dollars, 2% in Swiss franc and 2% in Japanese yen. Some economists refer to the developing states’ inability to borrow abroad in their own currency as the “original sin”, describing it as one of the most important sources of national debt crises (see Eichengreen B., Hausmann R., Panizza U., 2003, Currency mismatches, debt intolerance and original sin: why they are not the same and why it matters).
However, the dangers of foreign debt financing are not just associated with currency risk. Foreign investors, irrespective of the currency in which they hold the given country’s debt, are regarded as a less stable source of financing than domestic investors. To provide an example: a London trader will immediately react to changing market conditions, sell Polish bonds and transfer his capital to other markets that will guarantee a higher rate of return or a similar rate of return with lower risk. This is particularly problematic if there is a slump in the economy, when a refusal to refinance debt may result in skyrocketing servicing costs and sovereign debt crisis (see Calvo G, 2005, Emerging capital markets in turmoil; Rajan R., 2010, Fault Lines: How Hidden Fractures Still Threaten the World Economy). Theoretically, domestic investors may also take this path, but in practice they are always more reluctant to transfer their capital to other markets. Japan is an oft-quoted example of this rule: its sovereign debt amounts to ca. 250% of GDP, yet it is principally financed by domestic savings. Consequently, the country’s financial situation is relatively stable and its debt servicing costs are among the lowest in the world. The case of Greece or Spain, which were both affected by sovereign debt crises despite a lower debt to GDP rate than in Japan, is completely opposite. The example of Greece also demonstrates that a high share of foreign investors in financing debt may, in extreme cases, limit the possibilities of pursuing an autonomous economic policy. When shaping the debt structure, it is also worth noticing one other simple relationship: the interest rate on debt held by domestic investors contributes to the income of domestic institutions or citizens. Such interest increases domestic savings or consumption, and to a certain extent returns to the state budget.
The risks associated with foreign financing of sovereign debt are only revealed in times of crisis, which is why there is relatively low media coverage of this problem in Poland. Yet this is all the more reason not to ignore it. In order to reverse the trend of the growing share of foreign debt holders, we need to both increase domestic savings, in particular among households and natural persons, and amend the policy of issuing debt by the Ministry of Finance.
——————–
The article was originally published in Polish by Obserwator Finansowy on January 14, 2016.